Credit Cycles and A Minsky Framework

Hyman Minsky is a classical go-to regarding boom-bust cycles, credit growth and financial (in)stability. This essay is a refresher on how credit cycles work and how we can apply Minsky’s framework to understand such cycles.

What is a Credit Cycle?

A credit cycle explains the availability and supply of credit to willing borrowers. The cycle begins with a period where funds are easy to borrow. Banks are more inclined to take on risk, generate additional returns and so on. They have lower interest rates, lower credit requirements etc.

Increased credit leads to increased risk on bank balance sheets, as well as a potential increase in inflation. 

This forces banks to raise rates, requirements etc. Eventually, expectations around income growth decline, which triggers increased defaults, which then leads to tighter credit. Lather, rinse, repeat.

Credit Cycle Chart

As Warren Mosler discusses in Soft-Currency Economics, banks lend when they want to lend, without regard for the Federal Reserve’s actions. They will then borrow reserves in the interbank lending markets.

Where this gets interesting is how credit impacts valuations. This credit impact leads to vicious self-reinforcing feedback loops.

The Credit-Asset Feedback Loop

It is important to remember that the purpose of borrowing is usually consumption, or investment – i.e. some form of demand/spending. One man’s spending is another man’s income. If I pay you $5 for bread, you now have $5 to spend on whatever you want.. 

Assets are typically valued on cash flows. More specifically, the present value of those future cash flow streams is discounted at some appropriate interest rate. –

We see more borrowing in low-interest rate environments.. This affects asset values in two ways:

  1. The higher borrowing leads to higher spending which leads to higher incomes (that filter down to cash flows)
  2. The interest rate remaining low may have an impact on the discount rate 

This causes a natural rise in asset value (rising tide lifts all ships, kinda deal). To a lesser extent, the impact is brought singularly around by leveraged speculation, where the purchase of assets is brought around by higher borrowing.

However, this also possesses a self-reinforcing mechanism. The rise in asset prices causes collateral values to rise, which in turn leads to elevated credit extension.

This then causes spending to rise, and this causes asset prices to rise. This creates another self-reinforcing loop until interest rates rise, collateral requirements rise or some sort of event forces greater delinquencies. We’ve seen various cases of this behavior.

The Japanese Experiment, the 1980’s

Japan had a policy of window lending, where the Bank of Japan would handpick which sectors/industries received funding. This led to various issues across Japan and some ridiculous valuations. For example, the Imperial Palace in Tokyo was worth more than the entire state of California. 

The Japanese government had put together an incentive structure that fostered “investment”, speculation and easy access to credit. This led to excessive access to credit. Here’s a great chart showing what happened:

The cycle broke when the BoJ tightened, and asset prices had collapsed by 1992. The decline in asset prices brought various problems, including the high rate of NPL (non-performing loans) for various financial institutions, and the government stepped in to begin the process of what is widely known as the “zombification” of Japanese companies.

Who was Hyman Minsky?

Hyman Minsky was an economist with unorthodox ideas. Ideas about the importance of a central bank playing the role of lender of last resort, while stressing against the dangers of over-accumulating private debt in financial markets.

Some of his ideas can be found in Why Minsky Matters by Randall Wray. Here’s an example of one of his “unorthodox” ideas: 

“Minsky’s extension was to add the financial theory of investment, stressing that modern investment is expensive and must be financed—and it is the financing that generates structural fragility. During an upswing, profit-seeking firms and banks become more optimistic, taking on riskier financial structures. Firms commit larger portions of expected revenues to debt service. Lenders accept smaller down payments and lower quality collateral.”

Minsky Cycles

Minsky’s cycles can be stylized to the following diagram:

The important part is his simple idea of how stability breeds instability. The issue with stability is it changes expectations, which leads to substantial changes in lending. People have a tendency to extrapolate recent events far into the future. If we haven’t had a recession recently, people will assume the good times will continue. 

This means people (and banks) are more eager to borrow. Banks assume the periods of stability continue and are willing to make riskier and riskier loans. The scene of the housing market is “rock solid” in The Big Short comes to mind. 

A Minsky Moment

Eventually, this comes to a “Minsky Moment”, and it begins to unravel – and defaults rise. Banks cut back risk, and this slowly feeds on itself till the Federal Reserve (or other central banks) step in or the government steps in to help the financial system remain solvent – this phase of the business cycle is what scared Hyman Minsky so much, that he issued warnings against high levels of private debt.

Now, where are we at the moment? It’s a lot harder to tell where we are while looking at the windshield – and some part of the Fed’s policy is reacting to inflation caused by higher demand as well as supply constraints. 

At this point, it becomes more debatable, but yet we’re seeing the housing market pulling back a bit more, as well as revolving credit (shorter-term loans, etc) is expected to decrease.

Subscribe To Our Newsletter

Brandon Beylo

Value Investor

Brandon has been a professional investor focusing on value for over 13 years, spending his time in small to micro-cap companies, spin-offs, SPACs, and deep value liquidation situations. Over time, he’s developed a deeper understanding for what deep-value investing actually means, and refined his philosophy to include any business trading at a wild discount to what he thinks its worth in 3-5 years.

Brandon has a tenacious passion for investing, broad-based learning, and business. He previously worked for several leading investment firms before joining the team at Macro Ops. He lives by the famous Munger mantra of trying to get a little smarter each day.

AK

Investing & Personal Finance

AK is the founder of Macro Ops and the host of Fallible.

He started out in corporate economics for a Fortune 50 company before moving to a long/short equity investment firm.

With Macro Ops focused primarily on institutional clients, AK moved to servicing new investors just starting their journey. He takes the professional research and education produced at Macro Ops and breaks it down for beginners. The goal is to help clients find the best solution for their investing needs through effective education.

Tyler Kling

Volatility & Options Trader

Former trade desk manager at $100+ million family office where he oversaw multiple traders and helped develop cutting edge quantitative strategies in the derivatives market.

He worked as a consultant to the family office’s in-house fund of funds in the areas of portfolio manager evaluation and capital allocation.

Certified in Quantitative Finance from the Fitch Learning Center in London, England where he studied under famous quants such as Paul Wilmott.

Alex Barrow

Macro Trader

Founder and head macro trader at Macro Ops. Alex joined the US Marine Corps on his 18th birthday just one month after the 9/11 terrorist attacks. He subsequently spent a decade in the military. Serving in various capacities from scout sniper to interrogator and counterintelligence specialist. Following his military service, he worked as a contract intelligence professional for a number of US agencies (from the DIA to FBI) with a focus on counterintelligence and terrorist financing. He also spent time consulting for a tech company that specialized in building analytic software for finance and intelligence analysis.

After leaving the field of intelligence he went to work at a global macro hedge fund. He’s been professionally involved in markets since 2005, has consulted with a number of the leading names in the hedge fund space, and now manages his own family office while running Macro Ops. He’s published over 300 white papers on complex financial and macroeconomic topics, writes regularly about investment/market trends, and frequently speaks at conferences on trading and investing.

Macro Ops is a market research firm geared toward professional and experienced retail traders and investors. Macro Ops’ research has been featured in Forbes, Marketwatch, Business Insider, and Real Vision as well as a number of other leading publications.

You can find out more about Alex on his LinkedIn account here and also find him on Twitter where he frequently shares his market research.